1
2
3
Wealth and Want | |||||||
... because democracy alone is not enough to produce widely shared prosperity. | |||||||
Home | Essential Documents | Themes | All Documents | Authors | Glossary | Links | Contact Us |
Solution to School Finance Equity Dilemma in NY State: by
H. William Batt, Ph.D. The Court of Appeals has spoken. The State Legislature is challenged in response to find an additional $4 to 6 Billion to support the New York City School System, as described by the continuing Campaign for Fiscal Equity, an organization expressly designed to press for this resolution. Where will the money come from? It can come from only three possible sources: taxes on land, labor, or capital. Land in economics refers to all natural resources — air, water, the radio spectrum — plus land in the more common sense of acreage and urban sites. Unfortunately some neoclassical economists have effectively hidden and defined land out of existence, classifying it as capital, a grave mistake. This blinds many otherwise proficient students of economics and public finance to an obvious solution to this school finance crisis. Negative consequences of taxing labor and capital are profound. Taxing labor makes people work harder for less, that is for fewer of the things needed to support their families. Taxing capital, whether in the form of sales, savings, investments or equipment, incurs what is called “deadweight loss,” which puts an enterprise or region at an economic disadvantage. In contrast, if land is the tax base, there is no such loss. Clearly the same amount of land remains after land is taxed, as advocates of taxing the economic rent from land point out. The beneficial effects of taxing land have been noted by at least eight Nobel Prize-winning economists. Moreover, taxing land value – or location value – comports with all the textbook principles of sound tax theory. Indeed the more the economic rent of land is collected as a public revenue source, the greater the positive effects:
More than simply fostering better land use patterns, taxing land positively affects the economic vitality of a region, as shown in economic models, and in many actual examples. In 1982, Harrisburg, Pennsylvania was adjudged the second most depressed city in the nation under Federal distress criteria. Since that city’s phase-in of ever greater tax rates on land than on improvements, Mayor Stephen Reed notes that “Harrisburg has registered in excess of $3.1 billion in new investment. The number of businesses on the City’s tax rolls has increased from 1,908 to more than 5,900. Taxable real estate values have increased from an aggregate of $212 million to over $1.6 billion. The number of vacant properties has been cut by 85%.” The crime rate has been reduced 54% and the fire rate has dropped over 76%. Mayor Reed, re-elected continually since 1982, was just named one of the world’s most outstanding mayors. The City’s tax rate on land values is six times the rate on improvements. Twenty other Pennsylvania cities are now following suit. A tax on land values is eminently fair. It correlates highly with ability to pay. At the same time it serves as a benefit fee or user charge. Look first at matters of ability to pay or what may be called vertical equity. Households that own no land pay no land taxes even indirectly. Land, being “inelastic” or fixed in supply, means land owners cannot pass taxes forward to tenants. Taxes on structures can be shifted, but not the taxes on land. Thus the roughly one third of all households who are tenants, largely poor people, pay no property taxes. Of those that do own real estate -- homeowners, businesses, industries, and farmers – roughly half the aggregate burden in normal circumstances is paid by non-residential titleholders. Valuable parcels are typically located in the urban centers, and homeowners are at the urban peripheries. Remote farmland usually is inconsequential for tax revenue – if it isn’t protected in any case by other save-harmless clauses. Maps of land value typically look like those showing elevation above sea level, downtowns constituting the peaks. Empirical studies on the incidence of the property tax also show that it is progressive. At the same time it fares well by the other criterion of fairness, payment according to use. It is timely to note the effect of a land tax on the market price of real estate. It is well understood that buildings depreciate over time. Just as cars, computers, and factory equipment get old and obsolete even with maintenance, so do buildings. The rise in the market price of real estate comes from the appreciation of land, not from the homes or commercial buildings on the land. What creates this land value? In part it reflects the overall entrepreneurial activity in a location, rather than what any given titleholder does to the site. It also reflects the general vitality of a neighborhood or region. And it very much results from the totality of public facilities and services serving a locality. In sum, the value of land is community created. Land speculation may be understood as the attempt by owners, who apparently have little interest in tapping the productive potential of their sites, to ride the upward market trends and to reap these socially created land values. Often the owners reap these gains by waiting to be bought out by public ventures after suitable time passes. John Stuart Mill noted that
This does not prevent opportunistic speculators from pirating the public birthright when the opportunity arises. A century ago commentator William Riordan aptly portrayed New York ex-Senator George Washington Plunkitt’s saying.
But when a land tax is in place, the economic rent is recovered by the community so that land doesn’t rise in market price. It is stabilized. And there is no opportunity for such trickery. Real estate, especially residential property, thereby becomes more affordable. The greater the tax on land parcels, the greater the downward pressure on market prices. A land tax is the only tax that actually works to foster economic growth. The higher the tax on land value, the greater the incentive to economic vitality. This was recognized in a notable article in Fortune Magazine over two decades ago. It is this logic, taken in total, that invites consideration of a land value tax, administered statewide at a single rate, as a solution to New York State’s need to come up with $5 billion. Keeping in mind once more that the higher the tax on land the more it drives down the market price of real estate, and the higher the tax the more it removes the deadweight loss hampering economic development, it should become clear that instituting such a measure would solve the problem of securing the necessary revenue. With sound land assessment statewide, a rate can be calculated that will bring in the required total. Down the road, the sales prices of such parcels may well be lower while titleholders pay more “up front.” But even this prospect needs to be qualified, as increased activity may work in the opposite direction. The most likely question is how the burden will be borne. Much of the obligation will fall on parcels that are underused relative to their value – often locations not as productive as they potentially could be. This will provide an incentive to their improvement, so that their contribution to neighborhood and regional economic health will further enhance overall site values. If at the same time local taxes on improvements are phased out, as is occurring in Harrisburg and other Pennsylvania cities, the overall burden on parcels which contribute most to economic vitality will begin to decline relative to others. There is also the question of how to treat the case of the proverbial “poor widow” who may otherwise be driven out of her home. Such situations exist under current tax regimes, so that the application of a land tax constitutes a situation no different. What many states have done is to institute a practice of tax deferral, reserving the option for such titleholders to pay in full, with interest, when their homes are finally sold. This may come at time of transfer to other living arrangements or at death. Even with the recapture of deferred obligations, the increase in market prices is typically far greater than what taxes are due. One recent study notes that some 24 states employ property tax deferral provisions of one sort or another. This relief mechanism is far more just than others such as the oft-mentioned circuit-breaker or various tax credits or exemptions. The reason is that there is no net loss of tax revenue, and better use of residential infrastructure is likely to eventuate. There is no reason for young households to be locked out of housing opportunities for lack of ability to afford them, or for inheritors of elderly titleholders to reap the windfall gains from what is essentially the accretion of economic rent to the value of property sites. A statewide tax on land values would foster efficient economic policies to serve both upstate and downstate regions. Real estate values are far greater downstate than upstate, to the point that they make housing oft-times unaffordable. A statewide land value tax raises the necessary revenue by driving down market prices of real estate. Any parcel with a building to land ratio greater than the average would pay proportionately less with a tax shift off improvements. Any parcel with a below average ratio would pay more. Vacant lots in high value areas would bear the greatest increase, fostering their development. By recovering the economic rent that otherwise accretes, the economies are relieved of the deadweight loss, or excess burden, that exerts a dampening influence on market transactions. Again, the greater the tax, the greater the impetus to economic stimulation. In upstate regions, where the economic conditions are often moribund, the same factors apply to a lesser degree. The excess burden of economic rent is removed from land markets, and the impact on land use configurations is likely to be positive in as much as vacant and underused parcels will be most affected. Because the market prices of real estate, largely reflected in land values, are so much lower upstate than they are downstate, a single statewide tax rate on land values is likely to raise the greatest proportion of revenue from downstate regions, even while it is viewed as “fair” by its being a single statewide levy. This is important as a political consideration, because any other revenue stream from hard-pressed upstate regions will be catastrophic. Only a tax on land values can have a positive impact on economic circumstances. It remains to be explored how such a design will work – how accurate assessments of land value can be made to be, how easy it can be to educate the citizenry about a new paradigm of economics and taxation so that such a regime can be politically acceptable, and what proportion of the revenue stream will derive from various regions of the state. But these are empirical questions, and they can be quickly and easily determined. Computer-assisted assessment of land by itself is far easier to carry out than is assessment of land and building values together. Simulating the feasibility and the results would likely be achieved in a matter of hours. Apart from the technical feasibility and economic soundness of a statewide land value tax, there is a matter of its attractiveness as an environmental policy, and as a matter of economic and political justice. As an environmental policy, numerous organizations have come to see the virtues of a tax on land value; an extensive list can be found on the website of the Center for the Study of Economics. As a matter of political and economic justice, no name is more closely associated with these principles than the greatest advocate of this philosophy and approach: Henry George. At the time of his death in 1897, he was, along with Thomas Edison and Mark Twain, the most famous man in America. Today, a Google search on the words “economic justice” calls up among the top listings the Georgist websites, www.progress.org and www.earthrights.net. Two recent articles by this writer further explain how land value taxation can facilitate solutions to contemporary problems of a wide-ranging sort. In the final analysis, a statewide land tax is neither difficult nor alien
to New York State. Almost a decade ago, the City of Amsterdam sought to institute
it, and in fact did so for one year. Prior to so doing a legal ruling was necessary
to deem it constitutional in New York, and the already available assessment
roll separation of land values from totals made the shift a matter of a small
computer adjustment. Unfortunately, however, the assessments were of poor quality,
and titleholders blamed the land value tax regime for the disparities they
noticed perhaps for the first time. The policy was rescinded, but not before
many lessons were gained about its future implementation. What are the alternatives? There are none. Every other tax choice has strong downside consequences. Every other revenue stream penalizes real estate development, depresses investment and savings, discourages work, drives out economic expansion, and/or stifles commerce. If New York intends to address the challenge handed it by the Court, it will examine, and adopt, a statewide land value tax. It will lead the way to a revitalized New York State.
|
|
to
email this page to a friend: right click, choose "send"
|
||||||
Wealth
and Want
|
www.wealthandwant.com
|
|||||
... because democracy
alone hasn't yet led to a society in which all can
prosper
|