1
2
3
Wealth and Want | |||||||
... because democracy alone is not enough to produce widely shared prosperity. | |||||||
Home | Essential Documents | Themes | All Documents | Authors | Glossary | Links | Contact Us |
Nonpoint
Pollution:
Tractable Solutions to Intractable Problems Mason Gaffney
Paper delivered at Conference on
"Political, Institutional and Fiscal Alternatives to Accelerate
Nonpoint Pollution Programs," Milwaukee, December 9, 1987.
Reprinted in J. of Business Administration 18(1 & 2), 1988/89
(Special Issue: Future Directions for Economics), pp.
133-54.
The Special Challenge to Economic Thinking The Search for Surrogates Sources of Nonpoint Pollution What Problems are Created? What Problems are Unsolved by Excise Taxes on Surrogates? The Case of Forestry The Case of Urban Settlement The Case of Agriculture The Common Theme from Forest, City and Farm Solutions THE SPECIAL CHALLENGE TO ECONOMIC THINKING Nonpoint pollution goes right to a chink in the armor of conventionally trained economists (like myself) who are overtrained towards becoming protagonists of the price system. To the skeptical we are "free market freaks": eco‑freaks who are ‑nomic rather than ‑logical. Whatever our faults we are zealous, and carry the conviction of true belief. With the problem at hand, however, we can't do what we do best, that is call for price signals, punt, and slip away. The very name "nonpoint" pollution suggests that economists see this as just an odd bit of clutter, something "non‑regular" in their tidy world. Indeed, all pollution was an exception, an "externality," until recently (at least at my age it seems so). Then they learned you can meter effluents and tax them, or trade effluent rights around like private property. Thenceforth they could fit pollution right into existing models and ideologies with minimum intellectual strain. They were happy as Procrustes with a new guest. But we can't meter runoff — how frustrating.
Conventional price theory has been accused of mocking physics because it uses some elementary calculus, but if so it is a poor imitation: it deals with an imaginary world abstracted not just from friction but from space and time themselves. Space is relegated to one subdiscipline (location theory) and time to another (finance), so regular price theorists can spin their webs in purest abstraction, undistracted by these details. Most price theory is spaceless. Even location theory, at least the most common kind, conventionally treats cities as Euclidean points: the math is simpler that way. Newton could get away with it explaining planetary motion; students of urban sprawl can not. Economists are also ill-equipped to deal with ecology. Economists' "externalities" pour into a biosphere of interdependencies at least as complex as what economists purport to understand. Economists are too disposed to underrate the sensitivity, passion and numbers of Nature's votaries, and the real economic value of the philosophical values they celebrate. Fisheries economists are a notable exception, although they probably impose more economics on biology than vice versa. But most economists treat "eco‑freaks" as noisy nuisances. In the absence of a real ecologist I will presume to take their part. Economists, I hasten to add, are often useful citizens (both male and female, in spite of the male pronouns I use). Economists have been lumped with "soft scientists" — chemists really know how to hurt a fellow. But as a budgeteer allocating limited resources among competing ends — his favorite posture — it is often the economist, the soft scientist, who makes hard choices among hard scientists with soft programs. Another good use for economists, when mixed with natural scientists, is to temper extremism among those susceptible to technofascination. Some white-smocks, vested with prestige and authority once reserved for black-robes and red-coats, are given to optimistic fancies based on what science can do, as opposed to what slobs in the field actually will do. It is the economist's fate to study the latter, which accounts for his twisted smile and sardonic inside jokes. But sometimes a positive-thinking economist (there are a few) develops affirmative enthusiasms of his own for social and political programs that transcend particular technologies. Then he may need natural scientists to temper his zeal, as you may temper mine in what follows. THE SEARCH FOR SURROGATES The frustrated economist, unable to tax runoff, still has a bag of tricks. He looks for surrogates to tax, something in a sack or bottle that moves through a market: Aha! pesticides, fertilizers, salt, they'll do nicely to tax. Thus we will "internalize the externalities" and have "proper pricing of inputs" to create incentives for correct "trade-offs" in the "production functions," and we're nearly home. Well, halfway home. Well, we've made a start. A few problems remain. One is that a plurality of economists don't like the effluent charge approach anyway, even for point sources. They follow Coase and prefer to grant pollution entitlements to be traded in a free market. Incredibly (to me) this view has prevailed. In principle they profess not to care what worthy few get the original entitlements, but in practise a select company of ancient and honorable polluters get them. We now call these "offset rights," a new form of property. In the L.A. Basin (South Coast Air Quality Management District), a few have grown rich by establishing their respective histories of pollution which they can now sell to others who wish to continue this wholesome tradition. The demonstration effect on those contemplating new and as yet unregulated forms of pollution may be imagined. Those needing air to breathe? Well, according to the modern philosophers they can enter the market, buy up offset rights and retire them. Thus is fulfilled Robert Ingersoll's forecast a century ago that if some corporation could bottle the air they would charge us to breathe. It seems to confirm this dour warning from a former Secretary of Labor: "We soon discovered ... the
danger of allowing economic
policy to be dominated by business or financial interests or, which
usually comes to the same thing, orthodox economic analysis."
(Marshall, p.ix) (emphasis added)
The public has learned what is being done to it, finally, and is rebelling at the Coase logic, which only a Chicago economist could love. Offset rights are on the ropes. To simplify, therefore, I am not going to speculate how Coase might be applied to nonpoint, but just ignore it. I will treat effluent charges, and taxes on surrogates, as the conventional economic solution to pollution. But before leaving this there is a lesson in it. The holders of offset rights, whether "ancient and honorable" or "innocent purchasers," are demanding compensation. Never mind about asking them to pay the victims; they demand payment to stop! (Polakovic, 1987) They will probably get it, for if the system be changed, there will be a taking of something, which they claim is property. Such is the force of the Great Secular Superstition, that unearned gains are sacred, even those originating with something as unworthy as dumping crud on other human beings. This superstition is why effective control seems so expensive. My remarks will not be instructed by it. The surrogate approach may work through regulation and prohibition as well as taxation. Banning DDT and other organochlorines after 1972 has solved or prevented a lot of nonpoint problems, as you know. We may also tax or ban other pesticides of long residual life, stimulating a predictably successful quest for pesticides that self‑destruct after doing their job. But economists balk at absolutes. They have to admit that Rachel Carson and William Ruckelshaus and Russell Train won some games while economists sat on the bench, but they can show you things would be better with more tempered, measured responses. They prefer taxation to regulation: it inhibits rather than prohibits. It is more flexible, leaving latitude for applicator adaptation, recognizing the smoothness and continuity of production and damage and substitution functions. They would point out, for example, that making pesticides costlier would discourage the present practise of routine preventive or "insurance" spraying, and incent farmers to spray only when the bugs are up to an "economic threshold." Regulation to achieve the same end would be much more difficult, almost like a prescription drug system, presupposing an entomology profession with the moral and legal authority and tradition of the medical profession. Economists would point out that inhibition rather than prohibition is compatible with IPM, the optimizing solution. You've heard the traditional spiel, it is arguable. We can inhibit nonpoint pollution, in some ways optimally, by controlling surrogates. But let's look at the problems that would remain.
a. Taxes overlook the locational element,
whereas damages vary according to the site of the runoff.
A tax
imposed only in critical areas is avoidable by importing the input from
tax‑free zones. We could tax uniformly everywhere; but a uniform
tax on, say, nitrogen fertilizer would, in order to protect certain
waters, reduce yields from all lands. Presently that would pull
more acres into use, worsening other problems.
The underground economy
sometimes rises to the
surface, in episodes of rebellion, when deregulation is the vogue in
government. I favor some kinds of deregulation myself, but the
repressed cowboy psychology seizes these opportunities, too, to evade
legitimate taxes and prohibitions. b. Taxes raise revenue, and recipients develop vested interests in the revenue, interests which may come to override the regulatory purpose of the tax. The main issue of 19th century tariff debates was regulation vs. revenue. c. Excise taxes are not leakproof. The volume of bootleg cigarettes should give us pause, and I (a small fruit grower) have been tempted more than once with illicit supplies of Roundup. There is a huge underground economy in this country, a testament to man's irrepressible genius for tax evasion. There is a grand tradition of bailing out sellers with stocks on hand when a product is taxed or banned. Chlordane is a recent example. Dairy producers have been compensated when they could not sell their pesticide‑contaminated milk. (Carlson, 1977, p.319) To sell existing stocks tax free, when new ones are banned or taxed, creates a nice windfall. The 1972 Federal Pesticide Act also "provides for compensation to holders of patents on pesticides when registration removal occurs." (ibid.) The problem is, this whets the appetite for future windfalls. It is something like the terrorism treadmill where ransoming one hostage stimulates future kidnapping. Some clever people will develop new harmful products whose future prohibition or taxation will endow them with more windfalls, etc. ad inf. There are more than 50,000 agricultural pesticides registered in the U.S. (Gianessi, 1987, p.1), giving a notion of the possibilities. This is a second kind of "pesticide treadmill." Earl Heady has optimistically noted that herbicides are becoming more specific, tailored to certain crop problems (Nicol and Heady, 1977, p.339). Whatever else you can say about Roundup it is anything but that, and I wonder if we have yet to find an optimal set of incentives to bend the twig of research in desirable directions. d. A tax on nitrogen could be avoided by growing legumes. Not a bad idea, perhaps, all things considered, but it just scratches the surface of the kinds of substitution, some of it unpredictable, that can occur when you tax a surrogate rather than the damaging effluent itself. e. Taxing a surrogate fails to distinguish among individual applicators. It taxes the best for the sins of the worst, and credits the worst for the virtues of the best. Even if the rate be set optimally it will overtax the good and undertax the bad, and will not motivate anyone towards greater care and conscience to avoid harmful practises. f. The objectivity and moral authority of the professionals on whom we must rely to evaluate pesticides is not unquestioned. This is a delicate area, but we must face a certain public skepticism. The University of California has just lost a court case in which they were accused and convicted of violating the Hatch Act by favoring agribusiness over family farmers. They are appealing, and damage‑controlling, assuring the public (with public funds) what good people they really are, and how minimal the matter really was. Perhaps so: but they lost the case. What would happen if their objectivity were questioned on the grounds that they accept large, directed grants from pesticide producers, let faculty members consult for the same, and push faculty members into grantsmanship? Would Rachel Carson have found happiness in a UC Department of Entomology? Will Frances Moore Lappé? Was Earth Day conceived under a grant from Monsanto? U.C. Entomology Professor Robert van den Bosch was not amused by the dominance of what he called "the pesticide mafia." His Pesticide Conspiracy (1978), although tendentious, cites enough specifics to impugn several U.C. administrators, other universities, the USDA (that "wholly owned subsidiary" of the chemical industry), many congressmen, bankers and food processors, farm employers, most producers, salesmen and lobbyists, and at least one Nobel laureate. It is not a reassuring picture, nor is it reassuring that van den Bosch has been answered, if at all, by ridicule, personal abuse, and whispering. I draw the curtain of diplomacy over wherever these thoughts may lead. Moral authority or not, there are questions of efficiency and expedition. The mills of EPA may or may not grind exceeding fine, but they do grind exceedingly slowly. Since 1972 EPA has arrived at suspending only 79 active ingredients. Most of its "reregistration" reviews are still in some interim stage. Apparently industry advances new toxins much faster than EPA reviews them, so the inventory of pending reviews can only grow. g. The case for "proper pricing of inputs" is most persuasive when we can show that everything else in the system is working right first, as the optimal background we are to avoid distorting. But that is conspicuously untrue. When the system is balanced wrong anyway, what is one more distortion? It might even make things better, a viewpoint labeled "the theory of second best." In fact, land use decisions are superimposed on a settlement pattern based on massive market failure in land. The phenomena rather imprecisely called "land speculation" and "absentee ownership" betray market failure; and no one disputes there is massive regulatory failure in pricing and subsidizing transportation, which in turn determine land rents and values. Result: the land market is not efficient; land is not properly priced and allocated to begin with. This is the thread I will follow, although it may run afoul of The Great Secular Superstition. SOURCES OF NONPOINT POLLUTION All pollution is originally "nonpoint." It only becomes "point" pollution when someone has taken the trouble of gathering it at a small orifice in order to control it, often for the benefit of others. If we then tax point polluters while exempting nonpoint we will impair the incentive to control. That of course is why we are conferring now, and why we are looking at taxing surrogates. Taxing and banning surrogates has a place, perhaps a big place in any control program. But it may not touch many sources of nonpoint pollution. Let's list them here; see what damage they do (next section); and then see what remains unsolved by taxing and banning surrogates. Major sources of nonpoint pollution are:
"Construction" is usually added, but
construction
per se is innocent and should not bear the onus. It is
rather grading,
the destruction that precedes construction on new lands, that
denudes land and allows runoff and blowing. Filling can
be
noxious, too, when it takes wetlands that otherwise help filter runoff
before it hits shellfish beds and beaches. Several writers treat salt runoff lightly. It
may be of small concern in this region, but it is of monumental moment
in the arid west. Downstream water becomes unusable, and water
pooling and exchanging, from which so many economies could result,
become much harder to negotiate ("my water is better than your water,"
etc.).
THE CASE OF FORESTRY The inadequacy of surrogate pollution taxation is exemplified by forestry. The main purposes of watershed protection have long been to regulate water flows, to reduce flooding and erosion, and sustain flows during droughts. Minimizing pesticide runoff is a worthy additional purpose, but not the sole one. Francisco Goya left hanging in The Prado two paintings of his beloved, La Maja Desnuda and La Maja Vestida. Some prefer the earthy Desnuda. When it comes to Mother Earth, however, she looks better Vestida in virgin verdure or some renewable replacement raiments. Gaia theorists, indeed, regard the biosphere as an integral part of the whole terrestrial organism. However you regard it, removing it is hazardous and damaging to the children of Earth. Denuded land is the source of almost all forest runoff problems. Erosion results from a combination of
a) Regeneration is economical
there, it pays for itself where trees grow fast;
b) Regeneration is fastest there, minimizing the exposure period of bare land; c) Logging roads may be shorter and less erosive there, because nearer to markets and on level land; d) The temporary loss of scenic beauty is less severe; e) The exposed bare land is less steep; f) Logging is cheaper and less destructive; selective logging is more feasible; g) Fire control is easier; h) Younger stands are more vigorous and naturally resistant to pests. The last point bears underscoring here. It points to how good forest management can minimize pest damage without heavy reliance on toxics. The spruce budworm, for example, wreaks damage mainly on trees weakened by age. To protect those older trees, whole forests, millions of acres in the northeast are sprayed, with tragic treadmill results. The tussock‑moth, over which so much organochlorine has been shed in the fir forests, damages trees mainly on poor growing sites. Trees on good sites withstand defoliation, green up, and grow with renewed vigor. The moral: stay off the poor sites. The method: utilize the good sites fully. Why aren't the good sites harvested early, replanted quickly, and utilized fully? One major reason lies in the tax system. a.
Replanting cost is not expensable for
income tax, it must be capitalized, hence not written off until decades
later when timber is harvested. Timber taxation was not
neglected, you may be sure, by Oregon Senator Packwood who shepherded
through our most recent tax reform; but timber lobbies have
deliberately traded this off to keep what they prize more, the capital
gains treatment of timber sales.
b.
Most states have substituted the yield tax
for the property tax. The result is a bias against early
harvesting. When you look at the whole system it also pushes
cutting pressure out to marginal lands. But a yield tax at a high
rate wholly destroys any incentive to restock marginal lands, once cut:
it makes them subeconomic to replant.
c.
Some states have virtually eliminated the
land value part of the property tax on timber, removing an incentive to
early reforestation. A tax based on land value continues
at a
steady level during the sterile downtime of land between harvest and
replanting, thus pricking holders in the most compelling way to
restock, while not taxing them at all for actually restocking. On
marginal land the tax base is zero (it being based on land value) so it
does not cause abandonment, nor make replanting any less economic than
it already is.
d.
When timber is standing the value added by
growth is partly unrecognized as taxable income. Timber
has been
a "capital asset" for income tax purposes since 1944. Not only is
much of the gain unrecognized as income, but any tax is deferred until
harvest. After timber is felled, value-added in the mills and
markets is "ordinary" income and bears the full fury of the tax
rates.
When timber is standing there is
no property tax, so
it need only grow fast enough to pay interest on its value. After
it is cut it must yield a rate of return high enough to cover a
property tax, too, not just on its stumpage value but also on the
value-added by harvesting, hauling, milling, shipping, storing,
merchandising, and constructing.
Forestry on public lands, ironically, manifests
similar biases, from a different set of incentives. William Hyde,
Marion Clawson and others have documented the pattern: undermanagement
of superior sites accompanied by premature invasion of steep, remote
sites as the Forest Service internalizes all its profits from timber
sales to build more roads (and its empire). Thus the dual result of income and property taxes is to defer harvest, increasing the volume of old, disease-prone timber standing on good land, and pushing logging pressure out to marginal lands. Many marginal lands are non‑regenerable. Logging there is simply mining, leaving La Tierra Desnuda and open to the elements indefinitely. Both private and public forestry generate specialists with information monopolies which they use to obscure these issues and divert us with others. An optimal solution would constructively combine and synthesize two apparently contrary concepts of land stewardship. THESIS:
Concept A says "Conserve for the
future."
ANTITHESIS: Concept B says "Stewardship means highest and best use." Landholders are responsible to use land now, in order to employ others (generate incomes), to produce goods (combat inflation), and pay taxes (avoid deficits). SYNTHESIS: Concept AB says do both, but in different places. Use the good lands intensively, grow timber early and often, thus relieve human pressure and help conserve the vulnerable, erosive lands. Until this is done, will optimal taxes on aerial sprays do much good? Some good, no doubt. But the main problems are deeper rooted and call for bolder measures. That is my basic message. Forestry suffers from cutting sprawl, quite analogous to urban sprawl. The center is neglected, so the action moves to submarginal fringes and damages what's left of the center. Let us now look at two more cases, urban sprawl itself, and agricultural sprawl, where the source of problems is analogous, and the implied solutions the same. THE CASE OF URBAN SETTLEMENT The central problem here is urban sprawl; the solution is compactness. More land urbanized means more urban runoff. But more people on given land may even mean less runoff per acre, e.g. at the threshold where sewering can economically replace a collection of septic tanks and leach lines. It certainly means less runoff per capita. It means better control of any given runoff. A compact, synergistic city is resource‑saving; sprawl is resource-wasting, using up more land, capital, materials, fuels, and air/water quality to substitute for direct human contacts and cooperation. Here are some items that sprawl maximizes or worsens:
Solutions to urban sprawl will involve at least these three courses: a)
Marginal-cost pricing of city
services, with a spatial or locational component. Example:
a
water-rate surcharge rising with pressure zones. Cheap city
services in the center, encouraging infill and centralization.
b) Renewal-oriented tax policy, especially in central cities. (Milwaukee needs this the worst way, having lost population and capital for many years now.) Renewal‑oriented property taxation means to impose higher tax rates on land than buildings (Breckenfeld). Former Mayor Dan Hoan favored this policy (Hoan, pp. 26-27), and what Hoan favored, Hoan did. Renewal-oriented property assessment accomplishes the same end by apportioning a higher share of assessed value to land, and less to buildings. During Hoan's tenure the City Assessor accomplished it by using the "building-residual" method of apportionment. He drew up, reproduced, and publicly distributed land value maps, on which every parcel was valued at its highest and best use, as determined by comparable sales in the neighborhood. This approach approximately triples the assessed value of land, as compared to current Milwaukee practise. c) Renewal-oriented spending and service policy. One guide to this is "tiered" zoning and planning, firm and consistent. Attorney Robert Freilich, the "father of growth control," has shown how to make this work in Ramapo, San Diego, and we hope soon in Riverside. When Dan Hoan was Mayor of Milwaukee, 1916-36, he oriented spending this way reflexively (Hoan, Chaps. 2,8), to serve the existing city rather than to expand it. Milwaukee was a city that worked — then. One may prefer other measures. More should be said about constraining the space demands of cars and trucks. But the point is that whatever measures one wants, they will have to cut much deeper than taxing pesticides and fertilizers. We are talking about major, radical readjustments of urban, tax and utility policies. THE CASE OF AGRICULTURE Farming manifests the same problem as forests and cities. Public policy suppresses full use of the best lands while subsidizing use and abuse of marginal lands. As we said of urban sprawl, the more land in use, the more runoff. Here are some elements that cause "agricultural sprawl." a)
Urban sprawl takes the best land out
of farming. Cities deserve the best land and get it, but
urban
sprawl inflates urban demand several times over. In the best
light the demand is premature. Much of it is just wrong, now and
forever.
Shock waves from exploding cities fan out through the entire hierarchy of farm land uses, but not as neatly as force travels through a row of steel balls in the lab. At each margin of supersession there is a transfer of chaos plus an increment. Citrus invades deciduous, deciduous sprawls out among vines and vegetables, these move into cotton, cotton pushes on alfalfa which displaces small grains which take over pasture which invades the forests, and at each margin there is a new contribution of sprawl, chaos or entropy, a loss of concentration and focus and good economic spatial organization of farm activities. b)
Land retirement programs, under
whatever label (there's been a new variation on the theme every few
years since 1933) put good land on ice
to support prices. Under
the resulting "price umbrella," marginal land enters production.
This is classic cartel behavior.
c) Surpluses
are destroyed at home, or
dumped (sold below cost) abroad, under Federal subsidy.
d) Some
crops associated with high
erosion receive strong support or protection: wheat, corn, cotton and
sugarbeets, for example.
e) SCS
funds are not allocated by need,
but per Senator. Aldo Leopold observed of SCS, "In our
attempt to
make conservation easy, we have made it trivial" (Leopold, p.
210). It is worse: we have made it a pork barrel, like rivers and
harbors and missile contracts. So instead of cover-cropping
problem lands we use SCS funds on lands that scarcely need them,
reducing their output and increasing the pressure to till marginal
lands.
f) We
raise a farmer's property tax
assessment for installing a truly conserving device like a Harvestore
— it is so visible. Yet it turns hay into silage.
The
other farmer who stores corn silage in an open bunker pays few taxes
while losing 1/3 to 1/2 of the product of an erosive culture.
Meantime we subsidize new and submarginal lands in dozens of ways. But on the farm as in the city, the more land, the more runoff. I have cited the Feds for the Westlands Water District draining into Kesterson Refuge, and the Wellton‑Mohawk Project draining into the Colorado River. The State of California is as bad. The whole arid southwest quarter of the Great Central Valley is being brought into cultivation using subsidized water from the California Water Project's Westside Canal. Promoters there have discovered another treadmill effect, the "groundwater treadmill" of local-depletion-and-state-rescue, a treadmill that seems good for any number of cycles. But salt runoff has reached such a pass that the next rescue requirement will be a "brine line" to the sea, a line whose outlet is as sought-for as a nuclear waste dump. South of the Tehachapis the MWD has its own variation, the Mulholland cycle. MWD frightens city voters with drought forecasts, secures entitlements to excess water, and dumps it on surrounding deserts to enrich land speculators there. While waiting for urban sprawl to reach them they farm with the mindset of short-term tenants, caring nothing for soil conservation or permanent farm improvements. Mulholland began the game in 1913, storing Owens Valley water in the San Fernando Valley (remember Chinatown with Faye Dunaway and Jack Nicholson?) It was too good not to replay; there have been several Sons of Chinatown. MWD is now watering an "avocado crescent" 200 miles north-south, with groves on slopes up to 45 degrees. Will pesticide taxation control those problems? Rather, toxic runoff is just another of several reasons why we must face up to radical review of our political-economic treadmills, driven as they are by what TIME Magazine has called The Great American System of Public Works for Private Profit. THE COMMON THEME FROM FOREST, CITY AND FARM Market failure, public programs and perverse incentives in the land market create a gross bias towards spreading out too much. This aggravates otherwise fairly tractable runoff problems. The more Tierra Desnuda, the more runoff. This perversion does not occur by accident. Spread and sprawl in forestry, cities and agriculture are common results of the dominant force driving American politics, the quest for unearned increments to land value. Thorstein Veblen in his final testament, Absentee Ownership, noted that American farmers ...have
always, ... wanted something more than their ... share of
the soil; not because they were driven by a felt need of doing more
than their fair share of work ..., but with a view to ... getting
a little something for nothing in allowing their holdings to be turned
to account (Veblen, pp. 138-40).
To enhance those values they will now invoke any complaisant higher power, and since God already did His bit by donating the Earth, they turn to Government. But the profile of land values is like a volcanic island. To raise the top and the slopes and the shores we must also raise the shallows above sea level, where they shed the waters and come into use. Rising population is one factor pushing up the profile of values, but not the strongest one. Increased demand per capita is the main factor. These demands include all the spurious demands described above, like the demand of government for land to "bank" and hold idle, and the demand of speculators "with a view to getting a little something for nothing." Veblen went on to say that farm technology adapts to the Procrustean bed of absentee ownership: rather than leading, technology lags changes wrought by the ownership pattern. Thus it is not "society" or "efficiency" alone that mandate inorganic monocultural chemical farming, but also the peculiar needs of absentee owners holding more land than they can work themselves or with their families. Logic of, by and for this minority is set up as logic for all. If this be true, or (more likely) partly true, it must be admitted that most academics go along and get along with this dominant minority. Organic farming, biological controls, appropriate technology, IPM, and other countervailing logics had to come from screwballs outside the system, plus a few martyrs and kamikazes inside it, dominated as it is by accommodating "regular fellows," "good old boys," noncontroversial administrators who "understand local needs" and "work with community leaders," and complaisant faculty who enjoy "credibility." Are we part of the problem? Let everyone debate that with his own conscience, and be fair enough to lose a few points. SOLUTIONS The solution is land stewardship, a new-old ethic to supplant the cowboy ethic in which western man has wallowed over several centuries of territorial expansion. To reprise from the section on forestry, we must synthesize two concepts of land stewardship. Concept A says "save for the future"; Concept B says put land to full use right now, to serve and employ people. Concept AB says do both, but each in the right place. Use the good land, use it well and fully, employ the workers, serve everyone's needs. Congregate and cooperate on central, low, flat, fertile ground, as efficient markets and efficient public policies would dictate anyway. Leave the marginal land in peace. But as we tiptoe into this new era let us not sell stewardship by making it too easy and trivial, lest we repeat the sorry history of SCS. We are all trained to be trivial, to make few ripples and no waves. We are conditioned by higher education, and disciplined by employers to accept and believe the basic premises of the system and contribute our mite, if any, only to reinforce or patch or adorn it. Hence the fascination of schemes like effluent charges and their analogues like excise taxes on surrogates. If those ripples look like waves to us, it shows how much we have to grow to deserve our ancestors. Excise taxes have their place, true, but the problems at hand are much vaster and deeper than little measures reach. Solutions call for basic reconstruction and reorientation more drastic than most of us dare contemplate. But let's try: it might even be fun. Dan Hoan had fun making Milwaukee work; he is as good a model as we need. |
|
to
email this page to a friend: right click, choose "send"
|
||||||
Wealth
and Want
|
www.wealthandwant.com
|
|||||
... because democracy
alone hasn't yet led to a society in which all can
prosper
|