Taxing Productive Activity
What we tax, we discourage. Do we want to tax productive activity, or would
we prefer to discourage land speculation and discourage dogs in the manger?
Louis Post: Outlines of Louis F. Post's
Lectures,
with Illustrative Notes and Charts (1894)
4. CONFORMITY TO GENERAL PRINCIPLES OF TAXATION
The single tax conforms most closely to the essential principles of Adam
Smith's four classical maxims, which are stated best by Henry George 19 as
follows:
The best tax by which public revenues can be raised is evidently that which
will closest conform to the following conditions:
- That it bear as lightly as possible upon production — so as least
to check the increase of the general fund from which taxes must be paid
and the community maintained. 20
- That it be easily and cheaply collected, and fall as directly as may
be upon the ultimate payers — so as to take from the people as little
as possible in addition to what it yields the government. 21
- That it be certain — so as to give the least opportunity for tyranny
or corruption on the part of officials, and the least temptation to law-breaking
and evasion on the part of the tax-payers. 22
- That it bear equally — so as to give no citizen an advantage or
put any at a disadvantage, as compared with others. 23
19. "Progress and Poverty," book viii. ch.iii.
20. This is the second part of Adam Smith's fourth maxim.
He states it as follows: "Every tax ought to be so contrived as
both to take out and to keep out of the pockets of the people as little
as possible over and above what it brings into the public treasury of
the state. A tax may either take out or keep out of the pockets of the
people a great deal more than it brings into the public treasury in the
four following ways: . . . Secondly, it may obstruct the industry of
the people, and discourage them from applying to certain branches of
business which might give maintenance and employment to great multitudes.
While it obliges the people to pay, it may thus diminish or perhaps destroy
some of the funds which might enable them more easily to do so."
21. This is the first part of Adam Smith's fourth maxim,
in which he condemns a tax that takes out of the pockets of the people
more than it brings into the public treasury.
a. Interference with Production
Indirect taxes tend to check production and cause scarcity, by obstructing the
processes of production. They fall upon men as they work, as they
do business, as they invest capital productively. 24 But the single
tax, which must be paid and be the same in amount regardless of whether the payer
works or plays, of whether he invests his capital productively or wastes it,
of whether he uses his land for the most productive purposes 26 or in lesser
degree or not at all, removes fiscal penalties from industry and thrift, and
tends to leave production free. It therefore conforms more closely than indirect
taxation to the first maxim quoted above.
24. "Taxation which falls upon the processes of production
interposes an artificial obstacle to the creation of wealth. Taxation
which falls upon labor as it is exerted, wealth as it is used as capital,
land as it is cultivated, will manifestly tend to discourage production
much more powerfully than taxation to the same amount levied upon laborers
whether they work or play, upon wealth whether used productively or unproductively,
or upon land whether cultivated or left waste" — Progress
and Poverty, book viii, ch. iii, subd. I.
... read the book
Bill Batt: Comment on Parts
of the NYS Legislative Tax Study Commission's 1985
study “Who Pays New York Taxes?”
Land value taxation, on the other hand, overcomes all these obstacles.
Locations are the beneficiaries of community services whether they are
improved or not. As has been forcefully argued by this writer and others
elsewhere,32 a tax on land value conforms to all the textbook principles
of sound tax theory. Some further considerations are worth reviewing,
however, when looking at ground rent as a flow rather than as a “present
value” stock. The technical ability to trace changes in the market
prices of sites – or as can also be understood, the variable flow
of ground rent to those sites – by the application of GIS (geographic
information systems) real-time recording of sales transactions invites
wholesale changes in the maintenance of cadastral data. The transmittal
of sales records as typically received in the offices of local governments
for purposes of title registration over to Assessors’ offices allows
for the possibility of a running real-time mapping of market values.
Given also that GIS algorithms can now calculate the land value proportions
reasonably accurately, this means that “landvaluescapes” are
easily created in ways analogous to maps that portray other common geographic
features. These landvaluescapes reflect the flow of ground rent through
local or regional economies, and can also be used to identify the areas
of greatest market vitality and enterprise. The flow of economic rent
can easily be taxed in ways that overcomes the mistaken notion that it
is a stock. Just as income is recognized as a flow of money, rent too
can (and should) be understood as such.
The question still begs to be answered, “why tax land?” And
what happens when we don’t tax land? Henry George answered this
more than a century ago more forcefully and clearly, perhaps, than anyone
has since. He recognized full well that the economic surplus not expended
by human hands or minds in the production of capital wealth gravitates
to land. Particular land sites come to reflect the value of their strategic
location for market exchanges by assuming a price for their monopoly
use. Regardless whether those who acquire title to such sites use them
to the full extent of their potential, the flow of rent to such locations
is commensurate with their full capacity. This is why John Stuart Mill
more than a century ago observed that, “Landlords grow richer in
their sleep without working, risking or economizing. The increase in
the value of land, arising as it does from the efforts of an entire community,
should belong to the community and not to the individual who might hold
title.”33 Absent its recovery by taxation this rent becomes a “free
lunch” to opportunistically situated titleholders. When offered
for sale, the projected rental value is capitalized in the present value
for purposes of attaching a market price and sold as a commodity. Yet
simple justice calls for the recovery in taxes what is the community’s
creation. Moreover, the failure to recover the land rent connected
to sites makes it necessary to tax productive activities in our economy,
and this leads to economic and technical inefficiency known as “deadweight
loss.”34 It means that the economy performs suboptimally.
Land, and by this Henry George meant any natural factor of production
not created by human hands or minds, is ours only to use, not to buy
or sell as a commodity. In the equally immortal words of Jefferson a
century earlier, “The earth belongs in usufruct to the living;
. . . [It is] given as a common stock for men to labor and live on.”35
This passage likely needs a bit of parsing for the modern reader. The
word usufruct, understood since Roman times, has almost passed from use
today. It means “the right to use the property of another so long
as its value is not diminished.”36 Note also that Jefferson regarded
the earth as a “common stock;” not allotted to individuals
with possessory titles. Only the phrase “to the living” might
be subject to challenge by forward-looking environmentalists who, taking
an idea from Native American cultures, argue that “we do not inherit
the earth from our ancestors; we borrow it from our children.” The
presumption that real property titles are acquired legitimately is a
claim that does not withstand scrutiny; rather all such titles owe their
origin ultimately to force or fraud.37
If we own the land sites that we occupy only in usufruct,
and the rent that derives from those sites is due to community
enterprise, it is not
a large logical leap to argue that the community’s
recovery of that rent should be the proper source of
taxation. This is the Georgist
argument: that the recapture of land rent is the proper – indeed
the natural – source of taxation.38 ... read the whole commentary
|
To
share this page with a friend: right click, choose "send," and
add your comments.
|
|
Red
links have not been visited; .
Green
links are pages you've seen |
Essential Documents
pertinent to this theme:
essential_documents |
|