Classical
Liberals
Dan Sullivan: Are you a Real
Libertarian, or a ROYAL Libertarian?
According to royal libertarians,
land becomes private property
when one mixes one's labor with it. And mixing what is yours with
what is not yours in order to own the whole thing is considered great
sport. But the notion is filled with problems. How much labor does it
take to claim land, and how much land can one claim for that labor?
And for how long can one make that claim?
According to classical liberals,
land belonged to the user for as
long as the land was being used, and no longer. But according to
royal libertarians, land belongs to the first user, forever. So, do
the oceans belong to the heirs of the first person to take a fish out
or put a boat in? Does someone who plows the same field each year own
only one field, while someone who plows a different field each year
owns dozens of fields? Should the builder of the first
transcontinental railroad own the continent? Shouldn't we at least
have to pay a toll to cross the tracks? Are there no common rights to
the earth at all? To royal libertarians there are not, but classical
liberals recognized that unlimited ownership of land never flowed
from use, but from the state:
A right of property in
movable things is admitted before
the establishment of government. A separate property in lands not till
after that establishment.... He who plants a field keeps possession of
it till he has gathered the produce, after which one has as good a
right as another to occupy it. Government must be established and laws
provided, before lands can be separately appropriated and their owner
protected in his possession. Till then the property is in the body of
the nation. --Thomas Jefferson ...
Classical liberals recognized that
exclusive access to land, and
especially to more land than one was using, was a privilege that
should be paid for, thereby eliminating the need for taxes. It is not
a fee for using land, but a fee for the state privilege of denying
use of that land to everyone else.
Men did not make the
earth.... It is the value of the
improvement only, and not the earth itself, that is individual
property.... Every proprietor owes to the community a ground rent for
the land which he holds. --Tom Paine, "Agrarian
Justice," paragraphs 11 to 15
Another means of silently lessening the inequality of
[landed]
property is to exempt all from taxation below a certain point, and to
tax the higher portions or property in geometrical progression as they
rise. --Thomas Jefferson
Today's land value tax advocates
consider graduated land value tax
to be unnecessary and problematic, leading to artificial subdivision
(and phony subdivision) of land. The point is that Jefferson, to whom
libertarians pay homage, considered land monopoly a great evil and
land value tax a remedy, as did many other classical liberals:
Ground rents are a
species of revenue which the owner,
in many cases, enjoys without any care or attention of his own. Ground
rents are, therefore, perhaps a species of revenue which can best bear
to have a peculiar tax imposed upon them. --Adam Smith
Landlords grow richer in their sleep, without working,
risking,
or economizing. The increase in the value of land, arising as it does
from the efforts of an entire community, should belong to the community
and not to the individual who might hold title. --John Stuart Mill
...
Socialist Confusions
The classical liberal distinctions between land, labor and
capital
were greatly confused by socialists, and particularly Marxists, who
substituted the fuzzy abstract term, "means of production," for all
three factors. They also blurred the distinction between common
property and state property, for socialists believed, as royalty also
believed, that they were the people.
Today, the confusions between land
and capital and between state
property and common property are shared by socialists and royal
libertarians, and only classical liberals keep these distinctions
clearly defined. Yet royal libertarians frequently duck the land
issue by charging that it is the classical liberals, not the royal
libertarians, who have embraced socialist ideas.... Read the whole piece
winstonchurchill.org: THE PEOPLE'S RIGHTS:
OPPORTUNITY LOST? (reviews)
Publisher's pamphlet,
circa 1970:
The republication of any Churchill work
after sixty
years is an event commanding widespread public interest. Such attention
is owed the rich desert of The People's Rights,
last published at the
culmination of the election campaign of 1909/10, when the speeches from
which Churchill compiled the book were delivered.
Many a reader will find himself astonished
that so
vivid a portrayal of one of the great men of our time should have lain
so long out of print. Yet modern readers will miss much of the value of
the book if it is read only for the brilliant and sometimes surprising
insight into this vital stage of Churchill's political development.
For the principles and aspirations set out
here are
not those of the individual, but the life force of the great movement
that reached its zenith in the Liberal Governments of Sir Henry
Campbell Bannerman and Herbert Asquith that followed the landslide
Liberal victory of 1906. If one dares
to summarise the purpose and
vision of Liberal leaders of that time, it was to bring in a society in
which the poverty and social injustice of the previous century would be
eradicated without diminishing the liberty and independence of the
individual. The incentive would remain to develop his abilities to the
full for the good of himself and of the community. ...
Apart from Free Trade, the great
economic and social issues were
taxation and the alleviation of poverty. The Liberals were concerned to
remove the basic cause of the problem -- not just to mitigate its
undesirable effects.
It was the American economist Henry George who, towards the end of
the 19th century, had examined the paradox of the age in his Progress and Poverty.
His principles had a major impact, first upon the radicals of Scotland
and Ireland, including Campbell Bannerman himself; and later upon the
policy of the Liberal Party.
Henry George
propounded that whilst people have the right to possess what they
produce, or receive in exchange for their work, there is no such right
to private ownership of the elements upon which all depend -- air,
water, sunshine and land. Indeed, George held the right of access to
these basic elements as strong and equal as the right to life itself,
and that if private ownership of basic elements is permitted,
suppression and exploitation of one class by another is inevitable. The consequent injustice must
become more acute as the community develops.
Thus it became a major point of Liberal policy to
shift taxation from production, and to raise taxation upon the value of
land, on the basis that this value, as
witnessed by the tremendously high prices even then demanded for
commercial land, is created not by any individual but by the existence
and work of the whole community. A natural source thus arises
from which the community may meet its growing needs without
discouraging production or inhibiting the growth of earnings.
The justice and
practicality of this proposition can rarely if ever have enjoyed a more
brilliant advocate than Winston Churchill, and today's reader is left
to wonder how different might be the present state of Britain had the
forces of social change pursued these principles to their enactment. As
it was, the great power and intellectual prowess of the Liberal
Movement, which had commanded worldwide admiration for the breadth and
nobility of its vision, was soon to be dissipated by war, internal
feuding and the fear of Bolshevism.
Under the cruel
heel of war and unemployment, Britons came to value security more and
independence less. The emphasis in social advance shifted to the
massive provision of public benefits, and the increasing intervention
of the State in almost every area of human activity. The two
World Wars and the great depression between them severed, to a great
extent, the line of liberal thought that had developed over the
previous century.
Of Churchill himself, one can only feel that he was
fated to be the great war leader. Certainly, opposition to communism
and later to the rise of European tyrannies dominated the remainder of
his political life. It is perhaps ironic that a reason so often given
for his dismissal in 1945 is that he was not capable of dealing with
social problems, and thus was unfit to be a peacetime leader.
The
People's Rights tells
a very different story and comes now not as a document of historic
interest but as a challenge to politicians, indeed to the entire
electorate, to consider again the causes of poverty and the basic
issues of social and economic justice. Perhaps current
disillusionment with politics springs from a sense that if justice in
the community can only be achieved at the expense of individual
liberty, the price -- especially in terms of ever-increasing taxation
and bureaucracy -- is too high to pay.
As a proposition that justice in the community and
the freedom of the individual are complementary and that taxes may be
raised without undermining either, The People's Rights comes as a major
contribution to current political and economic thought. Indeed it
deserves a place in the annals of Man's struggle for freedom and
yearning for a society in which the genius of every person would be
nurtured and the liberty of every person respected.
John Nixon's Review of The People's Rights
Churchill as Classical Liberal
Churchill's pre-World War I books tend to be
overlooked by casual students of The Great Man. which is unfortunate as
they are well written and present a great variety for the reader: four
war histories, a novel, a biography, a travelogue, three speech
compilations, and a political campaign statement, The People's Rights. ...
Read the whole piece
|
To
share this page with a friend: right click, choose "send," and
add your comments.
|
|
Red
links have not been visited; .
Green
links are pages you've seen |
Essential Documents
pertinent to this theme:
|
|