Render
unto the Community
see also: fruits, he who produces,
a synopsis of Robert V. Andelson and James M. Dawsey: From Wasteland to Promised land: Liberation
Theology for a Post-Marxist World
Claiming
the Promised Land: A New Jubilee for a New World
In the book of Joshua, we find that although the Promised Land is a
gift from God, it is a gift that has to be claimed. Even before the actual
conquest of the Promised Land, the Mosaic Law prescribed a method whereby possession
of land was to be rendered pleasing in God's sight. The Canaanites' claim was
forfeited by their idolatry, with human sacrifice and temple prostitution,
and by their exploitive, monopolistic social order. By contrast, Israel, to
make good its claim, had to institute a social order that would guard against
the desecration, pollution, and injustices of which its predecessors were guilty,
and would secure to each family and to every generation within the Hebrew commonwealth
the equal right to the use of the land, of which the Lord was recognized as
the sole absolute owner.
They began with a census of the tribes and families before the conquest
(Num. 26:1-51). Every tribe, excepting Levi, and within each tribe every family,
was to receive its proportionate share, according to size (Num. 26:55-56),
and ultimately, to ensure fairness, by lot (Num. 34:16-29). The actual distribution,
according to these provisions, was concluded at Shiloh (Josh. 19:51). According
to ancient historian Josephus, the territory was not divided into shares of
equal size but of equal agricultural value. The landmarks that protected these
allotments were protected by the public and solemn denunciation of a curse
against anyone who should dishonestly tamper with them (Deut. 27:11-16;
19:14).
As discovered again in our own century,
it is easier to devise a one-time fair apportionment of land than it is to
keep the system from falling apart. This is why the ancient law established
the Jubilee year. At the end of every fifty years, any alienated lands -- given
away, sold, or lost from unpaid debts -- would be restored to the original
families. Temporary possessors were to be compensated for any unexhausted
improvements they may have made on the land. Concentrated landownership, and
the division of society into landed and landless classes, was thereby prevented
from creeping into the system. The
Jubilee effectively took the profit out of landholding as such, leaving no
incentive for speculation. When it was observed -- and historical records indicate
that it was observed for long periods -- the Jubilee system successfully removed
the root cause of poverty from the Jewish society.
The influence of the Jubilee idea upon early Pennsylvania colonists is evidenced
by the inscription on the Liberty Bell of the biblical words enjoining the
Jubilee year: "Proclaim Liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants
thereof." (Lev. 25:10) The founder of Pennsylvania, William Penn, advocated
that all men be "tenants to the public", and to defray public expenses instituted
a tax on land.
Environmental concern also goes back
to biblical land laws. To prevent the exhaustion of the soil, a periodic
fallow was ordered. "During one year in every seven, the soil, left to the
influences of sun and frost, wind and rain, was to be allowed to 're-create'
itself after six years' cropping, exactly as the tiller of the soil renewed
his strength, after six days' work, by his Sabbath day's rest."
As noted, the tribe of Levi did not
share in the equal division of the land, since it was charged with carrying
out religious and public duties. Its members were entitled to an indemnity
from the eleven tribes who received the land that otherwise would have gone
to them. This indemnity was the tithe -- one-tenth of the
product from the land occupied by the eleven other tribes.
Here, in principle, is the formula
for a just land system in almost any time or place. The compensation to the
Levites maintained the substance of equal rights to land, alongside of and
compatible with unequal physical division of the land itself. As Frederick
Verinder pointed out in his book My Neighbour's Landmark, joint heirs of a
house may share it equally by occupying it equally or unequally but "paying
the rental into a common fund, from which each draws an equal share; or they
may let the whole house to someone else and divide the rent equally." So it is with land.
Sharing equally in the economic rent or value of land through the application
of that value to common uses from which all benefit, renders private ownership
and unequal partition of land morally and pragmatically benign.
The modern equivalent of removing one's
neighbor's landmark is thus not the private ownership of land per se, but rather
the private appropriation of land value. "The profit of the earth is
for all" (Eccles. 5:9). The Old Testament ethic, to assure everyone the same
natural opportunity, asserts that all people have an equal right to economic
rent, and the Levite tithe demonstrates that the socialization of rent offsets
the ethical and practical harm resulting from private land ownership. But there
is another basis for its advocacy: Rent should
be taken by society because it is a social product. Rent arises in large measure
from two societal phenomena: the mere presence of population, and community
activity in a particular area. More people means more demand for space
on which to live and work. Community activities such as roads, schools, protection,
parks, sewage, utilities and other public services, as well as the totality
of private commercial and cultural operations, all make land more productive
or desirable. It follows that a community which funds such improvements out
of its rent fund will be provided with a stable and growing fund with which
to maintain and improve them. And unlike conventional taxes, the collection
of this fund will enhance, not penalize, the production of wealth.
Individuals, in their bare capacity
as landowners, do nothing to produce land value. By withholding sites from
use, whether for speculation or for other reasons, they may generate scarcity,
artificially inflating rent, but this does not reflect any positive contribution
to production on the part of landowners.
While land value is not the only type of unearned increment, unearned
income resulting from such advantages as talent, genes or luck is not at the
expense of others. Even Karl Marx admitted: "The monopoly of property in land
is even the basis of the monopoly of capital." Marx could have -- but did not
-- champion the abolition of land monopoly; instead he advocated its transfer
from private into state hands. It was left to Henry George to expound how the universal
principles of justice found in the Mosaic model could be applied to the modern
age in all its economic aspects -- rural and urban, agricultural and industrial,
technologically undeveloped or advanced.
What George advocated was to leave
land titles in private hands but to appropriate land rent via the existing
machinery of property taxation. "I do not propose either to purchase or to
confiscate private property in land. The first would be unjust; the second,
needless....It is not necessary to confiscate land; it is only necessary to
confiscate rent." No owner or tenant would be expropriated or evicted. No limit
would be placed on the quantity of land one could hold, as long as the annual
rent were paid.
Coordinately with the capture
of rent as public revenue, taxes on products of human labor -- improvements,
personal property, services, commodities, wages, etc. -- would be reduced and
ultimately eliminated.
George considered his remedy no mere human contrivance. He saw the growth
of land value and the easy means of equitably distributing it as an expression
of benevolent supernatural design: "As civilization goes on... so do the common
wants increase and so does the necessity for public revenue arise. And so in
that value which attaches to land, not by reason of anything the individual
does, but by reason of the growth of the community, is a provision intended
-- we may safely say intended -- to meet that social want."
George's remedy goes a long way to
stop current inequity and prevent future inequity. While past inequity, in
the form of accumulations of capital based on previous land speculation and
monopoly cannot be accurately redressed, these fortunes can be impelled to
serve the needs of the public via investment in production, not by further
investment in land speculation and monopoly.
Dependency theory, to the degree that it hits upon one of the causes
of Third World poverty in exploitation by foreign investors, can find in George's
land value tax the constructive practical approach it lacks. Neither erection
of trade barriers nor legal restriction of foreign ownership is called for.
As one Australian writer puts it:
(W)hen
investors from one country buy property in other countries they are seeking site
rent, which they hope to obtain directly from tenants, or indirectly
by selling land in the future when the price or capital value has increased....
The site rent that is so attractive to overseas investors can be kept in
the country quite easily - - by shifting taxation from labor onto land."
Because George asserted, "We must
make land common property," he is sometimes erroneously regarded as an advocate
of land nationalization. But, as we have seen, he was nothing of the sort. The
expropriation of land makes it practically impossible to fairly compensate
people for the improvements to land, which are their legitimate property. George's system renders
to the community what is due to the community, without doing any violence
to the wealth that has been fairly earned by productive workers. Read the whole synopsis
Charles T. Root — Not a Single Tax! (1925)
let us lay down and briefly defend the proposition that —
Taxation as a means of meeting the proper expenses of government is oppressive,
unjust, inexpedient and unnecessary.
This proposition will strike a good many readers as absurd, but all must at
least recognize the timeliness of the topic and the importance of any contribution
to the discussion of a subject which is agitating the whole civilized world,
for the methods, subjects and amounts of taxation are among the pressing problems
of every country.
The most obvious question which arises in the mind of anyone who reads for
the first time the proposition above laid down is this:
"If taxation is unnecessary, what is to take its place? Government and
its functions are increasingly expensive. They require a lot of money. Where
is it to come from?" The answer may be placed in the form of a second
proposition:
Every community, whatever its political name and extent — village, city,
state or province or nation — has its own normal, unfailing income,
growing with the growth of the community and always adequate to meet necessary
governmental
expenditure.
To explain: Every community has an indefeasible original right to the land
on which it exists, and to all the natural, unmodified properties and advantages
of that particular area of the earth's surface. To this land in its natural
state, undrained, unfenced, unfertilized, unplanted and unoccupied, including
its waters, its contents and its location, every individual in the community
(which may consist of any political unit selected) has an equal right, while
all the individuals together have a joint right to the value for use which
society has conferred upon these natural advantages.
This value for use is known as "Land Value," or by the not particularly
descriptive but generally adopted name of "Economic Rent."
Briefly defined the land value or economic rent of any piece of ground is
the largest annual amount voluntarily offered for the exclusive use of that
ground, or of an equivalent parcel, independent of improvements thereon. Every
holder or user of land pays economic rent, but he now pays most of it to the
wrong party. The aggregate economic rent of the territory occupied by any political
unit is, as has been stated above, always sufficient, usually more than sufficient,
for the legitimate expenses of the government of that unit. As also stated
above, the economic rent belongs to the community, and not to individual landowners.
On the other hand, the result of every utilization or enhancement of the natural
advantages of land (such as farm profits, the rent and selling value of buildings
and other improvements), when accomplished by an individual, belongs wholly
to that individual, and should never, and need never, be taken from him by
taxation.
One must be careful not to confuse land-value with the price of land. The
price of land is the sum demanded for the transference from one individual
to another of the privilege to collect and retain land-value and thus to divert
public earnings to private pockets. ...
But make it plain to the wayfaring man that taxation can be abolished and
will be abolished whenever the voters of any political unit so decree,
and a force of hope and purpose will be liberated which must bring nearer
the
time when the things that are the community's will be rendered to it, and
the things which are the individual's will be left in his unmolested possession.
The watchword of our friends the Georgeites is "A Single Tax." The
true slogan is "Not a Single Tax!"; and the triumph of the cause
behind that slogan would cut more of the taproots of poverty, vice and
social unrest than any other progressive step which is a legislative possibility.
read the whole article