Middlemen
Do we really want to provide another way to trickle income to our
(rather concentrated) business community? Can we afford for some to profit
and the rest of us to pay higher prices for essential goods?
Rev. A. C. Auchmuty: Gems from George,
a themed collection of excerpts from the writings of Henry
George (with links to sources)
THE mode of taxation is quite as important as the amount. As a small burden
badly placed may distress a horse that could carry with ease a much larger
one properly adjusted, so a people may be impoverished and their power of
producing wealth destroyed by taxation, which, if levied in another way,
could be borne with ease. — Progress & Poverty — Book
VIII, Chapter 3, Application of the Remedy: The Proposition Tried by the
Canons of Taxation
IF we impose a tax upon buildings, the users of buildings must finally pay
it, for the erection of buildings will cease until building rents become
high enough to pay the regular profit and the tax besides. If we
impose a tax upon manufactures or imported goods, the manufacturer or importer
will
charge it in a higher price to the jobber, the jobber to the retailer, and
the retailer to the consumer. Now, the consumer, on whom the tax thus ultimately
falls, must not only pay the amount of the tax, but also a profit on this
amount to everyone who has thus advanced it — for profit on the capital
he has advanced in paying taxes is as much required by each dealer as profit
on the capital he has advanced in paying for goods. — Progress & Poverty — Book
VIII, Chapter 3, Application of the Remedy: The Proposition Tried by the
Canons of Taxation
THE way taxes raise prices is by increasing the cost of production, and checking
supply. But land is not a thing of human production, and taxes upon rent cannot
check supply. Therefore though a tax on rent compels the landowners to pay
more, it gives them no power to obtain more for the use of their land, as it
in no way tends to reduce the supply of land. On the contrary, by compelling
those who hold land on speculation to sell or let for what they can get, a
tax on land values tends to increase the competition between owners, and thus
to reduce the price of land. — Progress & Poverty — Book
VIII, Chapter 3, Application of the Remedy: The Proposition Tried by the Canons
of Taxation
... go to "Gems from George"
Louis Post: Outlines of Louis F. Post's
Lectures,
with Illustrative Notes and Charts (1894)
The shifting of indirect taxes is accomplished by means of their tendency
to increase the prices of commodities on which they fall. Their magnitude
and incidence 6 are thereby disguised. It was for this reason that a great
French economist of the last century denounced them as "a scheme for
so plucking geese as to get the most feathers with the least squawking."7
Indirect taxation costs the real tax-payers much more than the government
receives, partly because the middlemen through whose hands taxed commodities
pass are able to exact compound profits upon the tax,8 and partly on account
of extraordinary expenses of original collection;9 it favors corruption
in government by concealing from the people the fact that they contribute
to the support of government; and it tends, by obstructing production,
to crush legitimate industry and establish monopolies.10 The questions
it raises are of vastly more concern than is indicated by the sum total
of public expenditures.
8. A tax upon shoes, paid in the first instance by shoe manufacturers, enters
into manufacturers' prices, and, together with the usual rate of profit upon
that amount of investment, is recovered from wholesalers. The tax and the
manufacturers' profit upon it then constitute part of the wholesale price
and are collected from retailers. The retailers in turn collect the tax with
all intermediate profits upon it, together with their :usual rate of profit
upon the whole, from final purchasers -- the consumers of shoes. Thus what
appears on the surface to be a tax upon shoe manufacturers proves upon examination
to be an indirect tax upon shoe consumers, who pay in an accumulation of
profits upon the tax considerably more than the government receives.
The effect would be the same if a tax upon their leather output were imposed
upon tanners. Tanners would add to the price of leather the amount of the
tax, plus their usual rate of profit upon a like investment, and collect
the whole, together with the cost of hides, of transportation, of tanning
and of selling, from shoe manufacturers, who would collect with their profit
from retailers, who would collect with their profit from shoe consumers.
The principle applies also when taxes are levied upon the stock or the sales
of merchants, or the money or credits of bankers; merchants add the tax with
the usual profit to the prices of their goods, and bankers add it to their
interest and discounts.
For example; a tax of $100,000 upon the output of manufacturers
or importers would, at 10 per cent as the manufacturing profit, cost
wholesalers $110,000;
at a profit of 10 per cent to wholesalers it would cost retailers $121,000,
and at 20 percent profit to retailers it would finally impose a tax burden
of $145,200 — being 45 per cent more than the government would
get. Upon most commodities the number of profits exceeds three, so that
indirect
taxes may frequently cost as much as 100 per cent, even when imposed
only upon what are commercially known as finished goods; when imposed
upon materials
also, the cost of collection might well run far above 200 percent in
addition to the first cost of maintaining the machinery of taxation.
It must not be supposed, however, that the recovery of indirect taxes from
the ultimate consumers of taxed goods is arbitrary. When shoe manufacturers,
or tanners, or merchants add taxes to prices, or bankers add them to interest,
it is not because they might do otherwise but choose to do this; it is because
the exigencies of trade compel them. Manufacturers, merchants, and other
tradesmen who carry on competitive businesses must on the average sell their
goods at cost plus the ordinary rate of profit, or go out of business. It
follows that any increase in cost of production tends to increase the price
of products. Now, a tax upon the output of business men, which they must
pay as a condition of doing their business, is as truly part of the cost
of their output as is the price of the materials they buy or the wages of
the men they hire. Therefore, such a tax upon business men tends to increase
the price of their products. And this tendency is more or less marked as
the tax is more or less great and competition more or less keen.
It is true that a moderate tax upon monopolized products,
such as trade-mark goods, proprietary medicines, patented articles and
copyright publications
is not necessarily shifted to consumers. The monopoly manufacturer whose
prices are not checked by cost of production, and are therefore as a rule
higher than competitive prices would be, may find it more profitable to
bear the burden of a tax that leaves him some profit, by preserving his
entire
custom, than to drive off part of his custom by adding the tax to his usual
prices. This is true also of a moderate import tax to the extent it falls
upon goods that are more cheaply transported from the place of production
to a foreign market where the import tax is imposed than to a home market
where the goods would be free of such a tax — products, for instance,
of a farm in Canada near to a New York town, but far away from any Canadian
town. If the tax be less than the difference in the cost of transportation
the producer will bear the burden of it; otherwise he will not. The ultimate
effect would be a reduction in the value of the Canadian land. Examples
which may be cited in opposition to the principle that import taxes are
indirect,
will upon examination prove to be of the character here described. Business
cannot be carried on at a loss — not for long. ...
4. CONFORMITY TO GENERAL PRINCIPLES OF TAXATION
The single tax conforms most closely to the essential principles of Adam
Smith's four classical maxims, which are stated best by Henry George 19 as
follows:
The best tax by which public revenues can be raised is evidently that which
will closest conform to the following conditions:
- That it bear as lightly as possible upon production — so as least
to check the increase of the general fund from which taxes must be paid
and the community maintained. 20
- That it be easily and cheaply collected, and fall as directly as may
be upon the ultimate payers — so as to take from the people
as little as possible in addition to what it yields the government. 21
- That it be certain — so as to give the least opportunity for tyranny
or corruption on the part of officials, and the least temptation to law-breaking
and evasion on the part of the tax-payers. 22
- That it bear equally — so as to give no citizen an advantage or
put any at a disadvantage, as compared with others. 23
19. "Progress and Poverty," book viii. ch.iii.
20. This is the second part of Adam Smith's fourth maxim.
He states it as follows: "Every tax ought to be so contrived as
both to take out and to keep out of the pockets of the people as little
as possible over and above what it brings into the public treasury of
the state. A tax may either take out or keep out of the pockets
of the people a great deal more than it brings into the public treasury
in the
four following ways: . . . Secondly, it may obstruct the industry of
the people, and discourage them from applying to certain branches of
business which might give maintenance and employment to great multitudes.
While it obliges the people to pay, it may thus diminish or perhaps destroy
some of the funds which might enable them more easily to do so."
21. This is the first part of Adam Smith's fourth maxim,
in which he condemns a tax that takes out of the pockets of the people
more than it brings into the public treasury.... read the book
Louis Post: Outlines of Louis F. Post's
Lectures,
with Illustrative Notes and Charts (1894) — Appendix: FAQ
Q8. What would be the expense of collecting the single tax as compared with
that of collecting present taxes?
A. Much less. It is easier to assess fairly, and easier to collect fully;
the machinery of assessment and collection would be simpler and cheaper,
and it would not enable first payers to collect the tax with profits upon
it from ultimate payers. ... read the book
Charles B. Fillebrown: A Catechism
of Natural Taxation, from Principles of
Natural Taxation (1917)
Q30. How would the single tax increase wages?
A. By gradually transferring to wages that portion of the current wealth that
now flows to privilege. In other words, it would widen and deepen the channel
of wages by enlarging opportunities for labor, and by increasing the purchasing
power of nominal wages through reduction of prices. On the other hand it would
narrow the channel of privilege by making the man who has a privilege pay for
it.
Q31. How can this transfer be effected?
A. By the taxation of privilege.
Q32. How much ultimately may wages be thus increased?
A. Fifty percent would be a low estimate.
Q33. What are fair prices and fair wages?
A. Prices unenhanced by privilege, and wages undiminished by taxation. ... read the whole article
|
To
share this page with a friend: right click, choose "send," and
add your comments.
|
|
Red
links have not been visited; .
Green
links are pages you've seen |
Essential Documents
pertinent to this theme:
essential_documents |
|