John Kenneth Galbraith
Frank Stilwell and Kirrily Jordan: The
Political Economy of Land: Putting Henry George in His Place
Enthusiastic proponents of Henry George’s ideas have often presented
them as a panacea for the economic, social and environmental problems that
beset contemporary society. Indeed, the Georgist analysis does have much
to offer. By more adequately addressing land as a unique economic, social
and ecological resource, it can help to reveal underlying causes of currently
pressing issues such as declining housing affordability, growing economic
inequality, and environmental decay.
The Georgist land tax ‘remedy’ can also play an important role
in the redress of these problems. However, there are limitations to the modern
application of George’s ideas, as outlined in this article. While a
uniform land tax is a necessary component in addressing contemporary political
economic problems, it is not sufficient. It needs to be set in the context
of a broader political economic analysis and policy program, also addressing
public housing, urban and regional policies, environmental taxes and regulations, ‘floors
and ceilings’ to limit income inequalities and macroeconomic stabilisation.
While the Georgist analysis redresses the general neglect of land in modern
economic orthodoxy, it is important not to go too far to the other extreme.
In other words, the important emphasis on land should not come at the expense
of attention to problems associated with labour and capital and to the complex
forms of government policy necessary for the balancing of contemporary economic,
social and ecological concerns. The Georgist analysis needs to be integrated
into a comprehensive political economic analysis of contemporary capitalism.
So what does ‘putting Henry George in his place’ entail? It
means recognising the political economic importance of land and
the potential social gains from the extension of land taxation. Equally,
it means recognising
the necessity of relating Georgist ideas and policy prescriptions
to a broader canvas of modern political economy, including the analytical
traditions associated
with Karl Marx, J. M. Keynes, and J. K. Galbraith, and modern
environmental economics. Henry George’s place is in good company. read
the whole article
Peter Barnes: Capitalism
3.0 — Chapter 2: A Short History of Capitalism (pages 15-32)
Sometime around 1950, capitalism entered a new phase. Until then, poverty
was a widely shared American experience. Wages were low, hours were long,
and unemployment was a wolf at almost every door. In the 1930s, it reached
25 percent.
This changed in the period following World War II. In 1958, economist
John Kenneth Galbraith wrote a best-seller called The Affluent Society
in which he noted that scarcity of goods was now a thing of the past
for a majority of Americans. “The ordinary individual has access
to amenities — foods, entertainment, personal transportation and
plumbing — in which not even the rich rejoiced a century ago,” Galbraith
observed. “So great has been the change that many of the desires
of the individual are no longer even evident to him. They become so only
as they are synthesized, elaborated, and nurtured by advertising and
salesmanship, and these, in turn, have become among our most important
and talented professions.”
This was a major phase change for capitalism. Before, people wanted
more goods than the economy could provide. Demand, in other words, exceeded
supply, and we lived in what might be called shortage capitalism. We
could also call it Capitalism 1.0.
After the change, we shifted into surplus capitalism, or what I call
Capitalism 2.0. In this version, there’s no limit to what corporations
can produce; their problem is finding buyers. A sizeable chunk of GDP
is spent to make people want this unneeded output. And credit is lavishly
extended so they can buy it.
This historic shift can be described another way. A century ago, our
chief scarcity was goods. It thus made sense to sacrifice other things
in pursuit of goods, and capitalism was masterful at doing this. Today
we’re waist-deep in thneeds, and our scarcities are different.
Among the middle classes, the top scarcities, I’d say, are time,
companionship, and community (see figure 2.2). Among the poor, there
remains a lack of goods, but that lack isn’t due to a shortage
of production capacity — it’s due to the poor’s inability
to pay. The critical scarcity here, in other words, is income. ... read
the whole chapter
|
To
share this page with a friend: right click, choose "send," and
add your comments.
|
related themes: see_also |
Red
links have not been visited; .
Green
links are pages you've seen |
Essential Documents
pertinent to this theme:
essential_documents |
|